Reflections on Islamic Economics

My story with the idea of Islamic Economics, my understanding of its practice over the ages and a vision

mnsiddiqi@hotmail.com

2011-2012

 

In what follows I narrate a story extending back about seventy years involving myself and the idea of Islamic economics. This is followed by my perception of what went on during the entire history of Muslim peoples since the call to Islam by the Prophet, peace be upon him, culminating in the current state of the idea in practice. The focus is on the twentieth century, especially on its second half, and  the first decade of the twenty-first century. More is said about the happenings in which I was a participant or close observer. There is much back and forth, as no chronological order is followed. That provides the spring board for imagining a future for the place of Islam in the economy of man. No such feat is possible, however, without surmising the shape of things to come during the next 50 years or so. In the end I bring the reader back to the present to sell an agenda for research and institution building that I like.

THE BEGINNINGS

As soon as I started reading I found myself surrounded in my home by, among other reading material, Islamic magazines (in Urdu) like the monthly Moulvi, Al-Tabligh, Al-Hilal and Al-Balagh ,and Tarjumanul Quran. It is difficult to pinpoint from where came the idea of combining Islamic education with the modern that made me write to Darul Ulum Deoband  and Nadwatul Ulama to get their Syllabuses when I was a student of class Seven in the Islamia Inter College, Gorakhpur. That was 1943. My earliest contact (through letter) with Maulana Syed Abul Ala Maududi’s  Darul Islam being in 1945,I must have read  Naya Nizam e Ta’leem (in which Maulana Maududi outlined an educational system bringing together modern social sciences and Islamic textual studies before an audience  at Nadwatul Ulama, Lucknow) after that date,  but definitely before the middle of 1947, when I passed Class Ten (called High School in India) along with my friend Abdul Haq Ansari. Instead of joining class Eleven the two of us started attending Arabic and Islamic classes in Anjuman Islamiyah, then headed by Maulana Ziaunnabi Abbasi who also happened to be the Amir ( President ) of local unit of Jama’at e Islami. By 1949,when I joined Aligarh Muslim University to study for the B.A. degree, not in the hard sciences I had studied till class XII, but in  Economics, along with Arabic and English Literature, the choice was finalized: To learn applying Islam to the economic aspect of life; to develop a discipline of economics reflecting Islamic values.

1950 to 1953  spent at Sanvi Darsgah, Jama’at e Islami Hind ,Rampur, including the last six months of 1953 at Madrasatul Islah, Saraimir, Azamgarh, were distinguished by lively interaction with several young college graduates inspired by similar ideas. Their choice of subject differed: economics, political science, philosophy, that made the experiment richer indeed. Further contacts with people young and old, graduates from religious seminaries and degree holders in modern sciences, brought in the realization that the idea of combining modern-secular and old-Islamic knowledge had very wide appeal, generating lot of expectations. I think a dis-enchantment with western ways of living—economic management, governance, family-life…was fairly widespread among the religiously inclined intellectuals, no less common than the desire to make the East a replica of the advanced West was among the secular elite. What else can explain the warmth with which we, the students of Sanvi Dasrsgah, were received by the likes of Dr. Zakir Husain (then Vice Chancellor of Aligarh Muslim University), Jamia Milliyah  Professor of economics, Mohammad Aaqil  Saheb and distinguished Professors at Osmania University, Hyderabad?

BACK TO ALIGARH

Back to Aligarh , in 1954 I was allowed to attend lectures of a renowned Marxist intellectual, Professor D. P. Mukherji-------- who was then head of the department of economics-------- even before my formal admission in 1956 to the same class that I had abruptly left for studying Arabic and Shariah at Rampur. Those were heady days for socialistic planning in India. Islam and everything Islamic was generally perceived as anti-socialistic, even pro-capitalistic, insofar as the Professors were concerned. But the student body was predominantly pro-everything-Islamic. That made the discussion lively, in the class-room as well as outside. We had some eminent visitors like Mrs. Joan Robinson and Professor J. R. Hicks whose talks were inevitably followed by discussions showing the intellectual divide of those times: Socialist planning versus free-enterprise. In retrospect, I feel my early choice of subjects to write on (Economic Enterprise in Islam, Islam’s Theory of Property, etc.), was influenced by the raging controversies of those days. I think this applies to almost all humans, what they learn and what they later teach is influenced by what they think is the need of the hour. With that age gone and new challenges emerging, it is easy to realize that the elaboration of any idea, and the idea of Islamic economics is no exception, in a particular time at a particular place may not necessarily suit another locale at another time. Even though the guiding principles are the same, their relative places, the emphases, change.

Many people had serious reservations about mixing Islam with economics. When I expressed my desire to register as a PhD student ( in 1960) with interest-free banking as my subject, I was wisely diverted to “A Critical Examination of the Recent Theories of Profit”®—a subject that would increase my competence in an area close to my subject of choice without endangering the prospects of earning a doctorate in economics. I consider myself lucky to have chosen that subject as it helped me focus on what is now universally regarded to be the crucial feature of man’s life on earth: uncertainty. This applies to almost every aspect of life, but its centrality in economic life is beyond doubt.

 Though very few in the department fully endorsed the idea of applying Islam, in its interest-prohibiting version, to economics, the idea caught on. We had colleagues at some other universities too. Our recently launched Journal, Islamic Thought [1954—1971] took the idea to neighboring countries too, as it got contributions from intellectuals and institutions outside India. Writings of Anwer Iqbal Quraishi, Maulana Maududi, Syed Qutb, Naiem Siddiqi, started elaborating upon an idea familiarized two decades earlier by Allama Iqbal, the poet: Relevance of Islam to economic management.

® Later published  by Asia, Bombay (1971)

Since the earliest writings on the subject, including those by Professor  Manazir Ahsan Geelani and Maulana Hifzur Rahman, there was great emphasis on behavioral aspects and institutional arrangements. State, representing the power dimension, was visible but not dominant except in some writings dubbed ‘Islamic Socialism.’

The First International Conference on Islamic Economics, scheduled for 1975 but actually held in 1976, was not the beginning of contacts between Muslim economists. In fact the conference followed widespread interest in Islamic economics. There were attempts to reshape financial institutions, reorganize Zakat collection and disbursement and revamp Awqaf, all over the newly independent Muslim countries in Asia and Africa. If discouraging greed, encouraging cooperation and calling upon hard work were recognized as the behavioral pivots of  Islamic economic resurgence, building institutions  enabling Muslims to act upon do’s and do-not’s of Islamic Law were seen as necessary means to the cherished ends. Early nineteen-sixties saw institution building initiatives in Egypt, Malaysia, the Philippines and Pakistan. Dr.Mohammad  Hameedullah has reported Imdad e Bahmi [mutual help] societies established in Hyderabad, India in late thirties of the last century. All these initiatives seem focused on helping Muslims in need of financing without getting involved with interest. There is a lesson here for those feeling bad about Islamic banking and finance becoming the chief expression of ‘Islamic economics’.

At the first International conference on Islamic economics we had the  Vice Chancellor, A M Khusro, and chairman of the Economics department, Mohammad Shabbir Khan(both now deceased) attending from Aligarh. Back to Aligarh we had a meeting in the department where the Vice Chancellor spoke highly of the conference and hinted at the desirability of including Islamic economics in our curriculum. Encouraged, I moved a resolution at the next available opportunity for introducing a course on economic thought in Islam as an optional at the MA level. The motion was lost. It remained one vote short of majority as the chairman and some teachers thought that adopting it will make the economics department look like the departments of  theology or Islamic studies . Two decades later, while I was still at Jeddah, the course was introduced. Later on, a number of students earned Ph. D degrees writing dissertations on subjects related to Islamic economics. A decade more down the road when the Academic Council adopted a resolution launching a post graduate diploma in Islamic banking and finance in the Faculty of Business Administration and providing for a full-fledged department of Islamic finance to be set up eventually, the then chairman of economics department, while supporting the motion, ruefully observed that the whole thing would be better housed in his department.

Several international conferences and seminars followed the conference in 1976. Universities put Islamic economics on their syllabuses. The number of research centers focusing on the idea has multiplied since the establishment of the one recommended by the First International Conference. Some sovereign states announced their intention to put the idea into practice. From nineteen-seventies till date, it has been an increasing crescendo. The idea of Islamic economics is recognized by more and more people; It is welcome in an increasing number of countries; the media is no longer indifferent____ All this within the framework of Islamic banking and finance as the chief expression of the idea in practice.

The thing to worry about is not the phenomenon of Islamic Banking and Finance emerging as the chief embodiment of the idea of Islamic economics but the particular form Islamic finance has assumed: Debt-financing .But more on this later.

MY MAIN WORKS

I include in this category, i.e. my main contributions to Islamic economics in its early days, Islam’s Theory of Property(Islam ka Nazariyah e Milkiyat),Banking Without Interest (Ghair Soodi Bank Kari) and Economic Enterprise in Islam. All three were completed and published in the mid-nineteen-sixties, with the exception of the last one which first appeared as a series of articles in Islamic Thought before being published in book form in 1971.

Islam ka Nazariyah e Milkiyat is the most comprehensive of all three. One of its chapters, Islami Riyasat ki ma’ashi Zimmedarian ( Economic Responsibilities of the Islamic State) was reproduced by some reputed magazines. It was also the most controversial, as for some people it smacked of socialism. I had laid great emphasis on the limits within which private ownership rights had to be exercised and the obligations towards others that individual’s ownership rights carried. In a long chapter I had enumerated the situations in which the social authority would intervene in the exercise of individual’s ownership rights. What was valued most was the numerous precedents from early Islamic history cited in each chapter. The late Dr. Mahmood Ghazi ( formerly federal minister and rector of the Islamic university, Islamabad) highlighted this feature when he rose to introduce me at a seminar in Kuala Lumpur in 2004. I think there was an appreciable change in the rhetoric of Islamists after this book. It was listed as one of the books recommended in the election manifesto of Jamaat e Islami Pakistan, issued in the early nineteen-seventies. In my later writings I must have moved away from highly regulated markets as I realized the crucial roles incentives played in bringing creativity and innovations to the fore. I realized this in a responding to a scholar’s comment in a Seminar held at Istanbul in 1995,about 20 years after the publication of Islam ka Nazariya e Milkiyat.

Economic Enterprise in Islam continues to inspire students despite its simple language and elementary economics. The reason: it tried to build an Islamic behavioral model from the scratch, in the light of the texts, the Quran and the Sunnah. Unlike other Islamic publications of those days, its backbone was not a critique of capitalism, socialism, etc. It focused exclusively on divine guidance relevant for economic life. The book was incomplete as it failed to elaborate upon the mechanism through which cooperation would play an effective role in a free market.

 Looking back after forty years , I wish I had paid more attention to the family or the household. Man is born in a family benefitting from loving care of the mother and other members of the family before one enters the market. One experiences gift relationship before the idea of exchange occurs to one. By projecting the market as the premier economic institution and obliterating the role of the family and the community, conventional economics wrongly projected competition as the center-piece of economics, relegating cooperation to a marginal position. I think we the Islamic economists were duped by the ruling ethos of the time. We neglected the rich Islamic literature on tadbeer e manzil ( management of the household) which had the potential of becoming the launching pad for an alternative economics, eschewing the  scarcity-selfishness-competition-maximization  route responsible for the current mess in human affairs.

Shirket aur Mudarabat ke Shar’I Usul  and Gahir Soodi Bank kari  (Shariah Princiles of Partnership and Profit- sharing and Banking Without Interest ) the two works complementing each other, were serialized in an Urdu magazine in the mid-nineteen sixties. That gave me an opportunity to consult a wide range of experts before these two books were published in book form in late nineteen sixties. My model was based on Sarakhsi’s  al-mudarib yudarib , what later came to be called two tier mudarabah. It would be another ten years before Murabaha entered the vocabulary of Islamic banking. All practical experimentations with the idea of Islamic banking till the mid-seventies of the last century, including the IDB and Dubai Islamic Bank, were murabaha-free, centered around the idea of risk-sharing. That had been the essence  of the contributions preceding my own, like those of Dr. Mohammad Uzair and the late Ahmad al-Najjar.

 It took some time before my books were published in English and then in Arabic.  I think the majority of my readers in Urdu had no idea about how modern fractional banking worked before they read my book. I also realized that it was not easy for traditional religious scholars to appreciate the role of financial intermediaries as distinct from trading partners. Both problems persist making it an uphill task to make Muslim masses take to banking earnestly.

I revisited the subject in mid nineteen-eighties(Issues in Islamic Banking) then again in early years of the twenty-first century (Riba, Bank Interest and the Rationale of its Prohibition) In both books accommodation of murabaha-banking is followed by a strong plea for return to risk sharing. But the Islamic finance industry continues to progress in the opposite direction, following the world- wide trend of shifting risks over to unwary households then, ultimately to the society, a trend captured well by Joseph Stiglitz in ,The Price of Inequality (2012).

ISLAMIC ECONOMICS IN THE WEST

My interaction with the West started in earnest in 1979 when I spent several weeks at Leicester, UK, as a guest of the Islamic Foundation, headed by Professor Khurshid Ahmad. This was followed by two months in 1981 in Chicago as a guest of the East-West University founded by Dr.Wasiullah Khan with the help of Dr. Abdullah Umar Naseef, the then Vice-Chancellor of King Abdulaziz University, Jeddah, where I worked (1978 -2000). My first foray in the West had lasted four months in 1972, looking,  unsuccessfully, for opportunities for post-doctoral research in Islamic economics and finance. Time was not ripe for the nascent American Muslim community to found Islamic financial institutions, but the ideas that later resulted in LaRiba and MSI were already afloat. Canadian Muslims could have been a little ahead, but I did not see any visible movement for building Islamic financial institutions in UK at that point of time. In Europe the Luxembourg Islamic Bank  came  up in the eighties, also Amir Mohammad al-Faisal’s initiatives: the Baden-Baden conference and Islamic Bank in Germany took place in the eighties. Darul Mal al-Islami and Saleh Kamil’s Al Barakah established Islamic financial institutions all over Middle East and North Africa. Meanwhile Malaysia and Indonesia were also moving in the same direction, sometime boosted by the above named leading institutions.

Zakat and Awqaf , the two other Islamic institution embodying the spirit of Islamic economics, were not entirely neglected. Several conferences were held, journals launched, arrangements long in slumber reactivated. The difference in attention is partly explained by the urgency one feels about do-not’s as compared to the do’s. Malaysians rightly saw Haj as part of the do package, insofar as Islamic economics is concerned. Attempts were afoot to link all Islamic economic initiatives to developmental urges of the regions inhabited by large Muslim populations, thus bridging the gulf between secular Muslim managers of the economy and standard bearers of Islam.

Islamic Economics in the West: HARVARD, UCLA, LSE, the Sorbonne and Madrid.

My two months at the University of California, Los Angeles as LaRiba Senior Visiting Scholar in the Center for Near Eastern Studies, established as a result of hard work by Dr. Yahya Abdur Rahman (the founder of LaRiba),  came after the Harvard Islamic Finance Forum started its yearly events in the late nineteen-nineties. Harvard Islamic Finance Forum continues to widen and deepen the understanding of the asset based financing promoted by Islamic banks. It has brought together western-secular and eastern-Islamic scholarships to focus on issues relevant to both East and West. On the one hand the Forum and similar events have helped spread the word that an alternative way of securing the end results of contemporary finance exists, and on the other hand we have succeeded in giving out the message that current practice of Islamic finance leaves much to be desired. There is the big difference regarding risk management. While conventional finance is engaged largely in risk-shifting, with the resulting increase in inequality and other evils, Islamic finance aspires to work for extending the range of risk-sharing. Islamic finance is still a work in progress. The LaRiba- UCLA venture ( starting September 24,2001,the date I reported for duty) ended prematurely as the financial sponsors had second thoughts (perhaps due to collapse of trust in the wake of 9/11)without creating any lasting impact. Meanwhile lectures on Islamic banking were held in Business Administration Department at UCLA and , in Claremont, at the Peter F Drucker Institute of Management. The Seminars in London School of Economics are instrumental in giving the idea a higher profile in the academia in UK, where several other Universities are involved with Islamic economics and finance. They also strengthen the continuing interaction between theoreticians and practitioners. Several other events in Europe and North America, sponsored by universities and/or industry, have generated public interest in the existence of an alternative to the conventional ways of finance. The Sorbonne in Paris and a college in Madrid are giving courses in Islamic finance. Italy too has hosted some conferences and some Islamic financial institutions are coming up in Russia and several countries of the former Communist Block, especially the Islamic republics in Central Asia. The phenomenon cannot be explained without universal recognition of some difference between the two, conventional and Islamic finance. For the common humanity Islamic economics has contemporaneous credibility through the only visible expression it has produced so far: the Islamic financial institutions. The situation may improve if the ongoing efforts in Sudan and Malaysia to eliminate the role of interest-bearing debt from monetary management succeed. But a bigger impact has to wait for activating the Islamic instruments for reducing inequality and ensuring universal need fulfillment. A ‘demonstration’ effect is possible only when states as well as NGOs and the citizens in general play more effective roles.

ISLAMIC ECONOMICS, TEACHING AND RESEARCH: The Missing dimensions

One of the core activities at the International Centre for Research in Islamic Economics at King Abdulaziz University, Jeddah,[now  Islamic Economics Institute]  was to promote teaching of Islamic economics. For many years meetings were organized bringing together teachers of the subject in  Saudi Universities .Similar efforts were made at the international level with the cooperation of the Islamic Research and Training Institute(IRTI),International Islamic University Malaysia, and the International School of Islamic Economics, Islamabad. The subject is now included in the program of almost every Muslim managed educational institution of higher learning all over the world. Along with modern schools, religious seminaries and madrasas have also adopted the practice. However a mist of artificiality surrounds the program, not to speak of the superficiality of its contents. I have touched upon some of the causes of this phenomenon in my paper: Islamization of Knowledge: Reflections on Priorities (American Journal of Islamic Social Sciences, vol. 28, issue 3 , Summer 2011.pp.15-35, available on my website www.siddiqi.com/mns ).Madrasas grapple with the same dilemma in accommodating this subject that they face in introducing any foreign language or modern  subject in their curriculum: Their inability to trim the traditional subjects to create space for new subjects. I got an angry response from quite a few Ulama when I suggested (on the occasion of an event organized by the Islamic Fiqh Academy India in 2009), in the light of personal experience, that there was some duplication in the teaching  of fiqh and hadith in madrasas. Time for introducing a new subject like Islamic economics in the program could perhaps be found by removing that duplication. For example, one can teach the chapter on taharah (purification& cleanliness) bringing together hadith and juristic derivation of rules of conduct based on them in one course instead of going over the same issue in two different courses on hadith and fiqh, often taught by different teachers. There are deeper methodological issues involved, best explained by the following anecdotes.

Of the over a dozen students whose theses I have supervised, half belonged to Ummul Qura, or Jami ‘at al Imam, both in Saudi Arabia. There are many more who consulted me and my colleagues in the Center for advice on what topic to select. There was one more supervisor, a faqih, from the student’s university whose say was final in selection of the topic. In an interesting case in which my suggestion was turned down, there was some field work involved: The concept of israf (extravagance) in Quran and Sunnah and its contemporary perception in various income strata of Muslim society in city X. Apathy towards empirical studies seems embedded in religious educational institutions. I never succeeded in persuading the Islamic Fiqh Academy of India or Idara e  Tahqeeq wa Tasneef Islami Aligarh to undertake any field study. This neglect of ground reality links up with other failings to produce the sterile scholarship afflicting us currently. The anecdotes that follow will explain further what dimensions are missing from our teaching and research.

About fifteen years ago a Professor giving a course at Harvard sent me some work sheets used in the context of discussing Islamic rules on riba/interest .All the relevant verses of Quran along with the main ahadith dealing with the subject were supplied, asking the student to derive and write down the rulings that could/should follow. Next, the student was required to look up authentic sources and note down the rulings actually given by Abu Haneefa, Shafi ‘i and other major authorities on Islamic Law. The student had to conclude by evaluating these rulings as well as defending his own views in a critical manner.

Around the same time I sat on an examination committee in the Islamic economics department of Ummul-Qura University at Makkah. In defending his Master’s thesis on labor relations in Islam, the student, after stating an issue involving employer-employee dispute ,happened to say: “I suggest ……”.To my  consternation, the chief examiner, a  Fiqh Professor, chided the student in harsh terms saying: ‘How dare you say “I”  suggest…? It is enough for us to learn what the great fuqaha and the aslaf have said and to transmit their opinions faithfully to posterity’.

 A student who had just earned a PhD degree in economics from the Aligarh Muslim University by writing a thesis on a subject related to Islamic finance, i.e. Murabaha , joined a course in Ifta’ (giving a juridical verdict) conducted by a religious seminary in Hyderabad, India. I was happy with his choice as the Faculty of Business Administration in our university had decided to have a full-fledged department of Islamic finance. This student who had a degree in Islamic sciences from an institution of good repute before he joined Aligarh ,would certainly gain much from the training to give Shariah verdicts he was likely to receive during the Ifta’ course, I thought. When I enquired from him, after he had earned the Ifta’ degree, about the method of training he told me: We were given specific queries and asked to consult particular fiqh books (,Hidayah or Shami, for example) to find the texts that answered the query, directly or indirectly.

We need some introspection indeed! It is up to our educationists to guess what challenges await Muslims in the decades to come and whether the methodology of the Fiqh Professor at Ummul Qura, or the Ifta’ course in Hyderabad is going to serve our purpose. Our current practices crush all independent thinking, extinguish any flicker of curiosity and kill all creativity. Absence of field work makes our research findings hollow and keeps all efforts tied to texts and logic, depriving young minds of the great benefits of enlarging the scope of conversation by observing the ground reality and including intuition and pragmatic considerations in dealing with their subjects of enquiry.

There are some other problems with our researches, especially when it involves Islamic history. A selective approach seems to have become the norm. Some of the modern-western writers find great gaps between theory and practice among other bad things in the Islamic past. Some, mostly Muslim scholars, paint an idealized picture and focus on lots of good things to report. Research suffers in both cases. When I wrote the paper: Public Borrowing in Islamic State [included in my book entitled: Role of the State in the Economy (1996) Leicester UK. The Islamic Foundation] it was sent to two referees as was the practice in the Center. The paper reports, among other things, some instances of the state borrowing from some non-Muslim lenders ,in order to be able to pay soldiers’ salaries on time ( in the third century Hijri, during Abbasid rule). For repayment the arrangement was to allow the lender to collect land revenues of a particular province. Sensing that the transaction smacked of riba, one of the referees, an eminent Professor, expressed great anguish, insisting that the particular narrative must be expunged from the paper. I think this is not the way we should handle our history. Assuming Muslims to be sincere in their quest for fairness, we nevertheless recognize variety of interpretations, insofar as the text of the law is concerned, and also recognize the role of compulsion of circumstances in deciding on actual policy. Departure of practice from theory, or rather a particular formulation of theory, is a fact of life. Man’s history is a story of intentionality being frustrated by circumstances beyond control. It should not be a cause of embarrassment. More important is to understand these circumstances and compulsions and the reasons why interpretations of texts differ. But for the sake of knowledge or hikmah, the supreme importance attaches to facts themselves. They qualify as amanah. Events should be reported as happened.

Something similar to my experience with the referee happened at the Makkah Conference of 1976 also. One of the points made in favor of an economy following the guidelines laid down by Islam was that it would be free of inflation. The eminent Muslim economists in the audience grimaced but thought it better not to challenge the Ulama making the claim. I got an opportunity to confront Sheikh Mohammad Qutb, the leading advocate of the view, citing historical evidence relating to the very first century of Islam. But the Sheikh dismissed history as of no relevance when it came to characteristics of the Islamic system he thought were derived from the texts of Quran and Sunnah.

A selective view of Islamic history combined with little understanding of the world we live in leads to false expectations that may later result in mass depression or global frustration. The KAU Islamic Economics Center once had some visitors, Professors and patrons, from an Islamic educational facility in Peshawar, Pakistan. Most queries by the guests naturally related to the idea of Islamic economics and how it could be put in practice in that part of the world, especially after the departure of the Russians from Afghanistan. One of the questions was:  “When and how will it be possible to do what the second caliph, Umar Farooq did: giving an annual stipend to every Muslim household?” That was the distinguishing feature of the Islamic economy: whereas modern states imposed taxes on people, Islamic state would give them stipends instead, he said.

I later realized that such naivety was not confined to ordinary folks. In one of the many in-house meetings with important visitors to the Kingdom to which we in the Center were often invited, Dr. Najmuddin  Erbakan a  former Turkish Prime Minister[June 1996  to  June 1997] distributed a document titled al-Ilaj (the Cure). In that document he had outlined future economic policies. It was full of utopian, impractical ideas. One example should suffice. Declaring currency and speculation to be at the root of many problems, the document proposed all producers of agricultural goods would surrender their produce to a government agency and get receipts that could be used in future to buy what they needed. Researchers in the Center--------including Mohammad El-Gari , Anas Zarqa and myself------------ prepared a rejoinder politely criticizing some of the proposals and suggesting alternatives. Dr. Muhammad Umar Zubair, a former Vice –Chancellor of KAU and at that time Professor in the Center took it to Istanbul to present it to Dr. Erbakan. But he did not, as he realized no criticism was welcome to our beloved leader. That in itself is a big problem with Islamic groups, especially the leaders, irrespective of their sectarian or political inclinations: little tolerance of dissent, little regard for democratic decision-making. Both are bad: naivety and intolerance, but their combination could be fatal.

IN SEARCH OF A METHODOLOGY

 

Even though Islamic scholars trained in the traditional way have now realized the need to study, research and teach non- traditional subjects like economics and political affairs, they have yet to develop appropriate methodologies for handling these subjects. There is a universal recognition of the difference between ibadat and mu ‘amalat insofar as the possible impact of changing times is concerned.        One can discriminate between social sciences and other subjects included in Islamic curricula on that basis. It is more important, however, to encourage critical reading, creative thinking and un-inhibited discussion on the issues involved in Islamic living in a globalizing world in twenty-first century. For the guardians of religious education in Islamic world the crucial thing is to realize that the traditional ways of teaching and research and jurisprudence centered on analogical reasoning often fail to guide us in changed circumstances. I had the good fortune to sit with traditional ulama and fiqh-scholars in class rooms, seminars and conferences, committees focusing on specific issues as well as exchanging views informally over a cup of tea. My interaction with traditionally trained Shariah Scholars started during the nineteen-forties and continues till date. Intensely feeling we needed to broaden the scope and extend the reach of our methods of thinking and arriving at decisions, I started drawing their attention to the rich Islamic heritage of thinking based on objectives of Shariah, public interest, and, in modern economic terminology, macroeconomic considerations, since early seventies of the last century. Ultimately I brought out a book in Urdu titled Maqasid e Shariet ( 2009, Islamabad and Delhi).In more than a dozen reviews I could come across, only few dealt with the main issue of methodology. The rest got lost into peripheral issues that found mention in the book while reporting some opinions. In that book, I have covered the evolution of Islamic finance ,in chapter six, to show how following the current methodology of patching  together some traditional contracts led us to legitimize  giving loans that had to be repaid with an added amount .They call it tawarruq. Tawarruq makes Islamic finance a replica of conventional finance. Had the consequences of flooding the economy with debts been taken into consideration by those who legitimized tawarruq, they would not have allowed it. In chapter three I suggested, in the light of texts from Quran and Sunnah, and precedents of the Companions of the Prophet, that reason and intuition should play an active role in our quest for fairness in economic and financial transactions and that relying exclusively on logical/analogical method was not the way our Prophet dealt with practical problems. I argued in favor of democratic decision making that implied tolerance of dissent and diversity. I sought to initiate a debate that would lead us to a methodology free of failings of our current methodology. Unfortunately the debate that ensued failed to focus on methodology. In the published reviews on my book Maqasid e shari ‘at, attention was mostly focused on the numerous examples of modern ijtihad ( none sponsored by me!) that claimed to be based on maqasid/masalih, on which the reviewer took a stand different from the one cited as example. In the burgeoning literature on the subject, there is little attention paid to the future: how maqasid based reasoning can help, and how the inevitable diversity of opinions could/should be handled. Instead of seeking endorsement for maqasid-based opinions with reference to possible future scenarios, most writers focus on yesterday’s issues claiming support for their opinions from similar happenings in the past that may or may not be relevant.

I think the issue on which critics as well as proponents of maqasid-based ijtihad need to focus is : how to handle the diversity of opinions that results from maqasid-based ijtihad? In Maqasid e Shariat I have suggested debating the issue, with participation from all walks of society, followed by decision by shura___ i.e. majority in a democratically elected body. Undoubtedly this is no ideal solution. It may need to be hedged by some other provisions to attain a balance between the spirit of divine Law and its letter.

 

LOGISTICS OF FURTHER RESEARCH

There is hardly any university in the world which will refuse to register a PhD student who chooses a topic related to the idea and practice of Islamic economics. Literature on the subject is found in all libraries worth the name. But no sizeable investment in research and publication on the subject is yet in sight. To the extent we can find any researches in progress, they are invariably text-based, discovering new meaning (s) in the age old texts in the light of linguistic rules. There is hardly any effort to look at the context in all its details: social, political and economic. Even when a research is meant for implementing a provision of Islamic Law in the contemporary situation, little attention is paid to the current ground reality. Look at what happened to the Diyat Law in case of accidental killing ( qatl  khata) as recommended by the Council for Islamic Ideology , a constitutional body in Pakistan, to the Government of General Ziaul Haq and enforced in form of Qisas and Diyat Ordinance 1980.( A countrywide strike by truckers, whom the new law made liable and penalized for anybody accidently killed by their truck, led to its withdrawal within days). I think something similar happened when the Sudanese government announced the integrated zakat and tax law (al-Qanun al-muwahhad li’l Zakat wa’l Daraib) in 1984.

ATTEMPTS AT ISLAMIZATION OF THE ECONOMY

It will be instructive to analyze what went wrong with the Islamization of the economy attempted by countries like Pakistan, Iran and Sudan, starting during the eighties of the last century. But it requires lots of data, information difficult to get and time and energy I do not have. We leave out the contentious question of how far those who ordered it were sincere and serious, focusing instead on the strategies adopted. One important issue is the relative efficacy of a top down approach as compared to a bottom up approach to Islamization. The second, more important issue relates to spirit versus form or maqasid versus analogically derived laws. The third and perhaps the thorniest issue is how and to what extent Islam can impact the economy in a plural society, characterized by religious and ethnic diversity, in the global village.

I do not have all the answers. In fact I doubt I have posed all the questions. But I do think this kind of analysis to be an important dimension of our stock taking. As regards the first question, it is evident the three countries named above adopted a top down approach. The private sector took little initiative in introducing Islamic values or evolving Islamic institutions. At least in some cases the authorities bear responsibility for this kind of apathy. Some decisions at the top seem to have been taken less with a view to ensuring efficiency and fairness and more to gain popular acclaim. Pakistan converted bank saving deposits into mudarabah accounts declaring that the rates of return will vary depending on the returns accruing to banks from the advances made to fund users. But the returns secured from the fund users were predetermined by a mark-up supposedly justified under the rubric of murabaha. As noted in a report of the Council for Islamic Ideology signed by the then chairman Justice Tanzeelur Rahman , the Council had advised to introduce profit-sharing in bank--fund-user relationship first but the suggestion was not accepted. Interest was back in picture as ‘mark- up’,  shifting the risks of business to fund-users. The conventional formula was back in saddle.

As emphasized later in this paper, the quest for fairness that characterizes Islamic economics and finance may lead to different contractual as well as institutional arrangements in different situations. These arrangements are better left to private parties, individuals, firms and institutions to devise, for which a degree of liberalization and releasing the chokehold of bureaucracy is necessary. This however is anathema for a top down approach especially in non-democratic regimes.

Sudan had the distinction of realizing the necessity of designing and operating mechanisms for monetary management free of interest simultaneously with eliminating interest from banks. It got good advice from competent economists. New tools of monetary policy, like CMC (Central Bank Musharakah Certificates) or Shamam, GMC (Govrnment Musharakah Certifictes), or Shahamah, and Sukuk al-Tamweel were devised. It is difficult to know the actual fate of these innovative measures as the Sudanese economy needed to borrow externally too, over and above the necessity of financing a war.

Iran has been exploring the possibility of introducing Participation Papers for mobilization of domestic savings since nineteen eighties. Now the Participation Papers have been made available to foreign investors too. The government of Iran had borrowed heavily from the central bank to finance social overheads and provide social goods. National participation papers (NPP), would be securities issued against these debts sold on the open market to control liquidity. It was proposed that this instrument should pay a dividend at least as large as the rate of return in the real sector of the economy but adjusted downward for the positive risk premium of the government. However the actual application of NPP was far more limited. It remains to be seen to what extent participation in profit actually replaces predetermined interest rates in external financial relations.

There are on-going efforts in Malaysia to bring monetary management as well as financial markets in line with the Shariah. Malaysia has the distinction of housing Tabung Haji, a saving-investment institution facilitating Haj journey sooner than later , that abjured interest , established as early as 1963.A fifth of the financial sector in Malaysia runs on non-interest basis, though still based on risk-shifting rather than risk-sharing. Similar market share is enjoyed by Islamic finance in the Gulf economies which too practice little risk-sharing. Dubai has the distinction of launching the first Islamic bank in the private sector, in 1975.Most innovations in Islamic finance originated from the Gulf, especially Bahrain, and Malaysia, probably due to a greater role the private sector could play in the financial sector as compared to private sector’s role in Pakistan, Iran and Sudan.  Intense competition from conventional banks is supposedly preventing Islamic Banks from any serious attempt to practice profit-sharing. When I asked a leading practitioner, in a conference on leasing held in a Gulf country about a decade ago about why the available share-in-profit models of leasing were not being tried, he said the aim was first to capture a substantial market share before attempting to introduce ways the market does not currently recognize. That day is yet to dawn, despite some advanced theoretical work on participatory mortgages.

It is an impressive record, the proliferation of Islamic financial institutions, from almost none in the beginning of nineteen- seventies to several hundreds to day. But there is a widespread feeling of dissatisfaction. The real thing is still awaited. All sceptics do not share the same reasons for not endorsing Islamic banking and finance as currently in vogue. Some would approve only those contractual forms that are prescribed and described in age-old fiqh books. Others would not approve of a monetary system that is not based on gold. Yet others debunk Islamic banks because they are not serving the poor. Some would not think of insurance at all, waiting for baitulmal instead to perform the relevant functions. For some the deciding factor is cost of services, Islamic banks are no good as their charges for services rendered are higher than those of the conventional banks. Despite the obvious loopholes in these objections people stick to some of them for the sake of giving vent to their disaffection. Sounds irrational! But Islamic banks cannot shrug them off as they remain a niche industry. Widespread customer dissatisfaction can destroy the industry. Only a comprehensive empirical study will reveal the causes of disaffection, opening the door to possible cures.

There has been a sea change in the world situation since the idea of Islamic economics re-emerged early last century. The first group of pioneers worked on the assumption of geographical boundaries that thwarted mobility of people as well as obstructed communication between them, sovereign nation states not recognizing any authority that could dictate to them and  economies that could be as closed as one desired. After seventy years these assumptions are barely sustainable. Geographical boundaries no longer obstruct communication and are fast losing their battle against mobility of persons. No economy can now remain closed to the world outside, the cost of doing so in terms of wellbeing being prohibitive. Supra-national authorities are increasingly able to dictate policies even to nations not willing to listen. States no longer have the power to impose policies on their unwilling citizens. No nation can afford to ignore what other nations think about it, much less the economically weaker ones.

 

 

ISLAMIC ECONOMICS IN HISTORY

Islam came with a vision of universally shared felicity. It is in that context that Islam generated a quest for fairness in finance. Justice had to prevail, exploitation ended and need –fulfillment for each and all, irrespective of race or creed, had to be ensured. The peculiar circumstances in the earliest days of Islam necessitated the task of increasing the strength of the ummah to preserve its independence and dignity, but the focus of the Messenger, peace upon him, remained deliverance of the humanity at large rather than uplifting a particular people. Guidelines were laid down by the Quran: Shared utilization of natural resources; Recognition of property rights; Encouragement of enterprise; Caring for others; Paying zakat; Dividing up inheritance; Prohibition of interest and gambling. In the economy of the first half century after Muslims migrated to Madinah, the markets were regulated and supervised but still remained largely free. The state played a positive role in lessening inequalities and promoting equity. The idea of Islamic economics stood in sharp contrast to the greed-ridden society before Islam in which the few exploited the many through riba, slavery and tribal privileges.

In the first five centuries of Islam, economic management in the lands under Islamic rule reflected the idea, in varying degrees though, but sufficient enough to give Islamic economy a distinctive stamp. Islamic laws of inheritance saved these lands from European-style feudalism that perpetuated serfdom. Zakat mitigated worst features of private ownership and Awqaf compensated for the incompetence and/or irresponsibility of the rulers. The dominant modes of financing revolved around risk-sharing rather than risk shifting. Comenda, the Islamic mudarabah contract, and trade credit based on trust, was able to finance  trade in the Mediterranean as well as in the Indian ocean. Trade, national as well as international, was largely free and taxes were few. Knowledge flowed unhampered and society valued inventors and innovators. The splendor of Al- Andalus, Fatimid Egypt and Mughal India owed itself to the idea of Islamic economics enshrined into institutions mentioned above as did the flowering of Law, Literature and the knowledge industry in general.

Somewhere down the road, maybe in the 13th century (sixth Hijri) onwards, things started to change. Free-thinking, free enterprise and free movement________ all suffered due to loss of self- confidence and erosion of trust. Optimism yielded to pessimism, hope to fear. The last two centuries, eighteenth and nineteenth, were the worst. The letter remained but the spirit was gone from the idea of Islamic economics as a shared attempt at good life (hayat  tayyebah).

Economic history of the Muslim peoples is not a well- researched subject. We know little about how the mainsprings of the idea, and the institutions embodying them, fared during the era of decline. Both the Ottomans and the Mughals were conscious of the distinctive nature of the economy of Muslim peoples. But they seem to have given little thought to its proper embodiment in a changing world. Instead of encouraging the private sector freely to meet the challenges of a (then) globalizing economy within the framework of Islamic values, they asked religious scholars and jurists to codify Islamic Law taking into consideration newly arising issues. Not only the creative spirit of the earlier days was gone and innovation became a taboo, the capacity to ‘adopt wisdom wherever found’ also yielded to lack of trust and fear of erring. The strategy of preserving the old structures was failing, paralyzing many and forcing some to take recourse to stratagems to adapt to structures and institutions imported from Europe. By the time Muslim lands got rid of colonial yoke during the middle of the twentieth century the idea of Islamic economics, widely acclaimed in almost every Muslim population but superficially developed in the academia, had gotten little contemporary expression. All that the avowedly Islamic regimes, like Pakistan, Iran and Sudan…could do is to maintain a veneer of being Islamic in economic management in a population yet to combine the morality inherent in the idea with the vigorous economic motivation that it takes to forge ahead.

A LESSON FROM ISLAMIC HISTORY

One of the many lessons to be learnt from history is the persistence of financial innovation, especially in the face of government regulation. Both innovation and regulation have their roles in the quest for efficiency and  fairness. While the first ensures progress in an uncertain world, the second, public supervision and regulation, is needed to protect and promote public interest and ensure social welfare. But the right mix is arrived at only by trial and error. In the sixth chapter of Maqasid e Shari ‘at  I have briefly traced the career of Suftajah, one of the earliest financial innovations. The controversies around that instrument remain unresolved. The following reveals another controversy in the history of economic management in Islam.

“…when the ships embarked to Medina, the caliph issued a sakk (a receipt, ration ticket) to the potential recipients of the amounts due to them. This gave the merchants the opportunity to buy and sell the tickets at a profit even before the wheat had arrived. One of those merchants was Hakim Ibn Hizam, already an important wheat merchant. Through his speculation with the tickets he was able to realize an enormous profit. However when this became known to Umar, he forced Hakim to donate his profits to be distributed as sadeqah. [ Muw’attah Imam Malik , and Ibn Hakam: Futuh Misr, as quoted in Mahmood Ibrahim: Merchant Capital and Islam,1990,University of Texas Press, Austin, page 124;. See Malik bin Anas: Muw’atta hadith #1313]

The text of Hadees # 1313 in Muw’atta as narrated by Yahya reads:

 ‘Hakim bin Hazam purchased wheat ordered (imported?) by Umar bin Khattab for the people. Hakim sold the wheat before taking possession of it. When this reached Umar he disapproved of the deal and said: Do not sell grain you purchased till after you take possession of it.’

Something similar happened during the regime of the Umayyid ruler Marwan bin al-Hakam. People started trading sukuk before actually taking possession of the wheat the sukuk represented. The practice was banned when two companions of the Prophet objected and told the ruler it amounted to riba [Muw’atta Imam Malik, hadith #1314]

As the following remarks by Nawawi in his commentary on Sahih of Muslim( who reported Marwan’s ban on selling sukuk in Hadees # 2818) makes clear, despite Umar’s stricture, the practice of selling sukuk---certificates of entitlement ---continued:

‘Al- Sikak is plural of Sakk which is a paper describing what is owed. Another plural is Sukuk. What is meant are  the papers issued by the ruler indicating the amount (of rations) due. It says the person holding it is entitled to a particular amount of wheat or any other grain. This ( paper) is what the person holding it sells before  taking possession of the grains (mentioned on it). Scholars differ regarding these deals, the correct stand according to our colleagues is permissibility of their sale’.

Nawawi then goes on to report the view of scholars who do not permit such deals. Then he notes that the permissibility view is the one to be preferred in view of What Abdurrazzaq reported in his Musannaf (# 131).’

As expected, the controversy relating to sale and purchase of sukuk continues till date.

One needs to track the historical record of this and similar episodes. As new situations arose new transactions would have emerged. The perennial questions  about fairness of new practices must have been answered differently by different people, those involved in practice, those to whom they turned for advice and those with a mandate to regulate the markets to ensure fairness.

    The lesson to be drawn is: In the quest for fairness in economic and financial matters the Texts help but only so far. Texts give the guideline but do not provide a blueprint. In drawing a blueprint for operationalizing the guidance given in the Text, reason and intuition have a role, and the social conditions also matter. That is where economic analysis, particularly macroeconomics, becomes necessary. What is sometimes called fiqh al-ma ‘alat (Fiqh of consequences) comes very near to it. But these leave wide scope for variety of interpretation and diversity of conclusions. All said and done, we have to live with differences of opinion and, therefore, of practice.


As noted above, I have tried to convince Shariah scholars not to rely solely on analogical reasoning in designing new financial products:  (
http://www.siddiqi.com/mns/Role_Of_Shariah_Experts.htm)

 It is necessary to take into consideration the impact a particular practice will have on the society as a whole. In Islamic jurisprudence there is a rich tradition of incorporating the consideration of masalih/maqasid/ma ‘alat into fresh legislations/legal verdicts/fatawa. But the overwhelming fear of diversity/difference of opinion prevents many Shariah scholars from deviating from the (often illusory) pursuit of logical consistency and uniformity and certainty of conclusions that their current methodology supposedly promises. As a result fiqh, which prompted creative thinking in the first phase of development of Islamic Economics is fast turning into an albatross.

What determines the fate of an idea, leadership or a population’s commitment?; the state or the market?; theory or practice?; traditions long established or external shocks? While this issue is debated let us turn to another no less important: What kind of future awaits mankind and what are its implications for Islamic economics?

………………………………………………………………………………………………..

THE FUTURE

Fifty year from now there will be a different world. If the pace of change during the last few decades is any indication we will have little poverty in the sense of people going without food, clothing, shelter, education and medical care. Inequality, and the indignity associated with it, rather than poverty and deprivation will be the main reason for conflict within and between nations. Distances will no longer constrain communication and interaction. Some of the gravest threats to humanity’s survival will come from outside ____ from the environment. This will necessitate greater cooperation and pass more of ‘economic management’ and ‘political governance’ to supra national cooperative organizations. Whether a single world currency will materialize is doubtful but disappearance of physically existing money seems to be a possibility. Children will still be borne to women, necessitating man-woman alliance. Some sort of family will continue, though with greater autonomy and equality between spouses. Health-care will still pose challenges though many existing diseases would have become curable. With the marked slowing of the rate of population increase before it reaches 9 billion  by 2070 and then starts shrinking® ,according to some estimates, the inner structure of population will call for special institutional arrangements for taking care of the elderly and nurturing the children, as more and more of the working age young are drawn into the work force. Group solidarity will still be largely based on race, language and cultural traditions but people will be more tolerant and appreciative of differences. Almost total urbanization of living spaces will give new meanings to neighbor-hood and call for innovative kinds of local governance. The economic landscape will be drastically changed due to new ways of providing services and new arrangements for production of goods. With the shifting power-balance from the West to the East and greater diffusion of economic muscle in the rest of the world, the role of power itself may decline leaving greater scope for cooperation at the global level.

What will be the implication of these changes for finance? Will financial intermediaries become redundant? Or, at the least, will their role decline? Will risk and uncertainty increase or decrease? Will markets be more transparent and more ‘complete’? Will the proliferation of NGOs further strengthen the Third Sector (the Voluntary Sector), downsizing the role of the state? While these questions will engage researchers for decades to come ( probably expanding the area of ‘unknown  unknowns’ simultaneously with increasing mankind’s stock of ‘known unknowns’), let us focus on Islamic economics in the broad sense. The inner self of men and women will continue to be relevant, perhaps gaining in importance. Technological revolutions of the last few millennia have not affected the crucial significance for the economy of how we look at life, death, and beyond. Affinity or alienation, empathy or hostility, Darwinian competition or

®Population forecasts differ widely. According to one UN study world population will reach 10.1 billion by year2100.[Google search 0n 27 February 2012].

 rational/ benevolent cooperation….these choices will determine the quality of life.

Research on exactly how much of a choice there really is will never be completed; it is perception that matters. The impact of Islam on economic management, as on other aspects of living will largely be determined by the interpretation of the Texts that wins the day. The losers will be those who stick to interpretations that long lost their relevance, the winners who succeed in interpreting the often multi-layered Texts in a way that answers the survival imperative and meets the needs and aspirations of the people.

Time to turn to specifics: I think debt-financing has had its day, something else is going to replace it. Most probably a whole range of asset linked securities catering to different appetites for risk-taking, but all based on risk-sharing, will take its place. “The elimination of debt markets will not deprive investors of diverse investment opportunities [ Askari H. et al, 2012,p.130]” . Maybe some kind of ‘participatory finance’ will replace much of the   ‘for-profit’ financial activities currently in vogue. Money and its management will undergo radical transformation as physical money dissolves into bits and bytes, geographical boundaries lose their relevance and political divisions succumb to economic necessity. Trade will flourish internationally and locally to a greater extent than what we characterize today as ‘domestic’ trade. The role of the state will increase in the context of cooperation at the international level but may yield some more space to voluntary organizations in the domestic economy. As international economy becomes more and more integrated, local interaction may also expand supplanting the quest for individuality that increased loneliness and anxiety without adding to happiness. Large multinational corporations will still have some advantages but local entrepreneurship serving niche markets will proliferate.

AGENDA FOR ISLAMIC ECONOMICS

At the theoretical level Islamic economists should continue to focus on how Islamic values could shape the behavior of economic agents leading to a market performance that improves the state of the world. Simultaneously they should model Islamic institutions of zakat, inheritance laws and risk-sharing into a macro- economy that works. Focusing on Islamic guidelines for economic management,

our research agenda should comprise designing institutions and structures that embody Islamic guiding principles.  One of the priority tasks is to make it easier for people to care for others, simultaneously with their own pursuits. This has a positive and a negative side, encapsulated in the maxim: No harming [la darar wa la dirar fi’l Islam].Given the will to do good, what one can do will depend on the information one has. This leads us to institutional arrangement for collecting and disseminating information, as information is a public good. The market does not perform the function of lessening information asymmetry between contracting parties efficiently. A bigger problem is the all- pervasive uncertainty that envelops the future. This in fact has been the main headache of mankind since day one. The bad news is: It is going to stay. The good news is, history teaches us that open minds and freedom to experiment and explore can see to it that we wade through the misty, hazy tomorrows unharmed. The test of life on earth, success in which would determine one’s place in afterlife inheres, perhaps, more in dealing with uncertainty and exercising personal judgment, than in obeying/disobeying unambiguous laws in unambiguously clear situations.

…………………………………………………………………………………………………..

 

 

 

…………………………………………………………………………………………………………………

A PROMISING FUURE

 

Do I see a reprieve from the suffocating hold of the traditional bookish approach to Islamic economics and finance? Yes, I do. Theory often follows practice. As the newly emerging pro-Islamic democracies take charge of domestic economic management and participate in international financial reform, new interpretations of the texts and innovative accommodations of the contexts will give the idea of Islamic economics a fresh impetus.  This is more likely to happen in countries which do not have oil wealth that enables them to enjoy the fruits of  globalization and  development without hard work and accommodation of diversity.

This is not to recommend doing nothing and leaving matters to politicians adept in the art of compromises. Quite the contrary, I think the current situation provides us with opportunities the like of which never arose during the past many centuries. I am referring to the coincidence of a crisis that shook the self-confidence of conventional economics and finance and resurgence of popular democracies in many Muslim countries that gave a boost to Muslim self-esteem. I consider it to be a boon that most of the first few countries to be blessed by this new flowering of Islam are not oil-rich countries. Let experts in the understanding of Texts, and those designing and putting into operation economic and financial arrangements meeting the exigencies of the situations at home and sustainable in a globalizing world, join hands. Let this exercise be cosmopolitan, not confined to Muslim countries. Let it not be a bid for Muslim empowerment but, as befits the nature of the Prophetic mission, an endeavor for humanity’s deliverance. The western world is listening and there is an impressive pool of Islamic economic and financial talent permanently residing in the West. Deeply engrossed in doing economics and finance the conventional way till now, they may be rudely shocked to find their mentors looking east for deliverance. They will come around, adding to the talent-pool dedicated to Islamic economics. Now is the time to speak out, after doing necessary home work. The priority task for the older generation of Islamic economists is to facilitate the home work.

The distinctive feature of Islamic approach to economic management is its focus on justice and fairness. The Quran lays great emphasis on  ‘adl and qist [57:25;16:90;6:152;4:58;4:135;2:82-83;5:8   ] and removal of zulm [38:21-24;4:10;4:29;4:75;2:278-9;2:140;16:144;16:21;30:28-29;18:57  ].Justice and fairness is the pivot of the Quranic notion of salah, the removal of whose antithesis  fasad is targeted [2:150-52 2:204-5;28:40;30:41;26:21;6:82;28:83;7:74  ]. Considered together with the dignity accorded to human beings[17:70 ] and the idea of all humans being brothers and sisters as created by one God[49 :13 ], their Lord, we have a clear agenda with a universal reach: to work for falah (felicity) for each and all.

 

So, where to begin? I greatly value historical and empirical research as argued in an earlier writing: (http://www.siddiqi.com/mns/Obstacles_To_Islamic_Economic_Research.htm)

I assume many Muslim populations in the past were as keen to live Islamic lives as we think we are. To various degrees, they too faced population increase and technological changes, even globalization, giving rise to new situations and, in economics and finance, necessitating new ways of doing business. We need to learn from the way they dealt with these situations.

The current crisis gave us an opportunity to draw world attention to the dark side of interest bearing debt financing. Adherence to interest-bearing debt financing  is rooted in, among other things,  the false perception that nothing else works. To demolish the falsehood we need showing how risk sharing interest-free arrangements worked for centuries. This has to be supplemented by theoretical models of sharing based financial system as well as by practical demonstrations wherever possible. I hope the newly emerging democratic scenario in the world of Islam will provide ample opportunities for such demonstration.

Despite the un-enviable record of countries that declared their allegiance to the idea of Islamic economics in the past, Muslim economists should offer them whatever services they can and encourage them to make fresh attempts. These attempts have a greater chance for success in the changing situation in the world at large. Democracies may have a better chance for exploring various alternatives. The grip of Western/conventional international financial institutions on the economies of Asia and Africa is loosening. As power balance between East and West shifts, the managers of eastern economies may be able to muster greater courage and develop the political will to leave the beaten path.

We must sincerely and with all seriousness, join the world-wide search for new financial arrangements that are less crisis- prone and more fair. Muslim economists should do it for their own countries of residence as well as at the world stage by associating with the ongoing efforts. Favorable geopolitical conditions  are crucial for the future of Islam in the world anyway. But in the field of finance Islam can have worldwide impact only by effective Muslim participation in solving humanity’s economic problems.

 

BIBLIOGRAPHY

 

Askari, Hossein, Zamir Iqbal, Nouredinne Krichene & Abbas Mirakhor (2012)Risk Sharing in Finance: The Islamic Finance Alternative.                         John Wiley & Sons (Asia)

Mawdudi, Maulana Syed Abul Ala(  )Naya Nizam e Ta’leem

Ibrahim, Mahmood (1990 )Merchant Capital and Islam. University of Texas Press, Austin TX.

Malik       Muatta

Ibn Abdul Barr(  ) Al-Isti  ‘ab

                            ( ) Usud al-Ghabah fi Ma  ‘rafat al-Sahabah

Ibn e Abdul Hakam(  ) Futuh Misr

Diamandis, Peter S and Steven Kotler (2012) Abundance. Simon & Shuster

_____________Country Focus: Sudan-Forgotten Centre of Islamic Finance, New Horizon(London) 1 April 2009

Mohammed  Ali Elgari ( 2009)The Islamic Perspective on Derivatives, Oxford Islamic Finance---Dar Al- Istismar

North, Douglass C.(2005 ) Understanding the Process of Economic Change(Princeton Economic History of the Western World)

Shiller, Robert J(2012) Finance for the Good Society

Hallaq,W B(2009)Sharia: Theory,Practice,Transformations.Cambridge University Press

Booth, William James (1995)Households :On the Moral Architecture of the Economy. Cornell University Press